Subscribe
Logo

ISET Economist Blog

On Imitation, Forbidden Fruits, and Sour Grapes
Friday, 13 December, 2013

For many observers, the Georgian job market is a mystery. Companies are bitterly complaining about a lack of engineers, forcing them to withhold the expansion of production capacities and to cut down investments. Yet Georgian young people, who could make good fortunes by studying technical subjects, prefer to learn the law, business administration and the like, qualifications that are oversupplied in the market and on average do not yield high salaries.

Young Georgians, lacking information on what sells well in the job market, apply a simple decision rule called the imitation heuristic:If you are clueless about what to do, do what everybody else does.” If everybody studies law, then there must be something good about that subject. Legions of people cannot err.

Imitation happens all the time in economic decision-making. Your friend invites you to a restaurant to which you have never been before. The menu is large and you do not know what to eat. What do you do? Well, you simply order the same dish as your friend. And maybe you have chosen that particular restaurant because it was the one that was most frequented by other people (“they cannot all be wrong!”). Imitation is also common in capital markets, where so-called herd behavior, i.e. everybody buying or selling the same assets, can lead to overshooting prices, bubbles, and crashes.

There are many explanations for why people imitate each other, some of which relate to evolutionary forces that shaped behavioral patterns millions of years ago. Indeed, imitation of behavior can be frequently observed among animals, for example when a swarm of fishes changes direction in a coordinated way. It was shown that rats apply the imitation heuristic in their food selection (see, for example, “Explaining Social Learning of Food Preferences without Aversions: An evolutionary Simulation Model of Norway Rats” by Jason Noble, Peter M. Todd, and Elio Tuci, in Proceedings: Biological Sciences, Vol. 268 (2001), pp. 141-149). Recently, it was shown in a game-theoretic model that imitation can be a winning strategy in many situations of social conflict (Peter Duersch, Jörg Oechssler, and Burkhard C. Schipper: "Unbeatable Imitation", Games and Economic Behavior, Vol. 76 (2012), pp. 88-96). The Georgian psychologist Dimitri Nadirashvili summarizes such findings in his book “Social-Psychological Influence” (in the Georgian language, Nekeri Publishers 2009) when he writes that “95% of people are imitators” (p. 143).

THE FORBIDDEN FRUIT IS SWEET…

Imitation may be behind other behavioral patterns we observe. For example, it is only possible to imitate if one knows what others are doing, yet in many situations, this information is not disclosed. In a competitive environment, scarcity is an indicator of what other people are consuming. So one can imitate other people’s behavior by simply consuming what is scarce.

In an experiment, psychologists let people choose absolutely identical cookies either from a vase with lots of cookies or from a vase with just a few cookies. The experimental subjects consistently favored the latter, and this effect was even stronger when “popularity” was mentioned as the reason for scarcity (Stephen Worchel, Jerry  Lee, and Akanbi Adwole: “Effect of Supply and Demand on Rating of Object Value”, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, Vol. 32 (1975), pp. 906-914).

Marketing specialists knew all along that the forbidden fruit is sweet. Therefore, we see many advertisements emphasizing the limitedness of a good. The obsession of humans with gold, a metal that is pretty useless for most practical purposes, may originate from this deep-rooted desire for scarce things. Standard microeconomic theory, on the other hand, takes the valuation of an economic good as exogenously given, independent of the availability of the good.

… AND IF YOU FAILED TO GET IT, IT WAS A SOUR GRAPE

What about people who succeeded to acquire a scarce item? They paid more just because it was scarce, not because the good yields higher utility. Will they not be frustrated once they find out that they bought something that is popular but does not yield a value justifying the high price?

Chances are that they won’t. As it turned out, people overvalue an item for which they paid too much. Likewise, they tend to derogate things they did not get, a psychological mechanism commonly referred to as the “Sour Grape Phenomenon”. It can be explained by the famous cognitive dissonance paradigm of the American psychologist Leon Festinger (1919-1989). Festinger postulated that people seek harmony between their beliefs and their behavior and when there is a discrepancy (a “cognitive dissonance”), they will change one of the two. The overpriced scarce good is bought and cannot be returned, so even if objectively it is plainly disappointing, the behavior cannot be undone. Yet the belief about the quality of the item is flexible. It is possible to autosuggest that something is great, even if objectively it is just mediocre.

Those who did not manage to obtain the limited item will feel cognitive dissonance, too. Though initially, they considered the object really desirable, they have to cope with the fact that they did not get it. Instead of admitting to themselves that they are failures, they will find it easier to just change their opinions about the value of the good.

The name “Sour Grape Phenomenon” comes from one of Aesop’s fables, beautifully put into rhymes by W.J. Linton in 1887:

“This Fox has a longing for grapes:
He jumps, but the bunch still escapes.
So he goes away sour;
And, 'tis said, to this hour
Declares that he's no taste for grapes. “

The graph shows how the “forbidden fruit” and “sour grape” effects might affect the standard economic diagram of supply and demand. The dotted line is the new demand curve that comes about once psychology has kicked in. In line with intuition, the psychological effects create a price range where demand increases when the price goes up.

FINAL

Let us try to overcome these irrational desires. And let the upcoming New Year sales be the first test for our rational minds!

The views and analysis in this article belong solely to the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the international School of Economics at TSU (ISET) or ISET Policty Institute.
Subscribe