Subscribe
Logo

ISET Economist Blog

Consumer Rights in Georgia
Friday, 07 March, 2014

On the 15th of March 1962, President John F. Kennedy delivered a seminal speech to the congress, outlining the four rights that he considered essential for consumers: the right to safety, the right to be informed, the right to choose, and the right to be heard. Ever since Kennedy’s speech, the idea of consumer protection blossomed both in theory and in practice. In this year, 52 years after Kennedy’s speech, Georgia will pass a new law on the protection of consumer rights. Let us have a look at consumer protection in general, in Georgia, and at the draft law that will enter the parliamentary process soon.

WHAT IS CONSUMER PROTECTION?

It is useful to distinguish two kinds of consumer rights, namely ex-ante rights and ex-post rights.

Ex-ante consumer protection refers to the time before the purchase was made. It prevents potential buyers from being deceived, it ensures product standards, and it helps consumers to make the right decisions.

For example, there are plenty of safety regulations in place for potentially dangerous technical products like chainsaws, electric bread cutters, and water boilers. In Europe, fuses must be so sensitive that you can throw your hair-dryer into the bathtub while taking a bath without suffering an electric shock. Before the electricity reaches your body, the fuse must already have blown (we do not recommend testing whether this really works).

Other standards refer to the way in which goods are produced. For example, in Europe and the USA, the attribute “organic” is legally protected. Organic food needs to be produced under certain standards that restrict the use of pesticides, fertilizer, etc. There are also laws that set standards for calling a product “beer”, “milk”, or “juice”. The latter must be made from fruits and water only (otherwise it can only be called “nectar”).

Also, the list of ingredients of foodstuff may be useful for a buyer. It helps vegetarians to avoid meat and people who suffer from a peanut allergy to avoid anaphylaxis. And the drastic warnings on cigarette packets, like “smoking kills”, “smoking causes cancer”, and even “smoking can cause erectile dysfunction”, may lead some smokers to abandon their unhealthy habits.

The most radical means of ex-ante consumer protection is banning a product from being sold. For example, in some countries, it is not allowed to sell leaded fuel and unpasteurized milk. And everywhere in the world, it is forbidden to sell hard drugs.

Ex-post consumer protection refers to the situation after the good was purchased. For example, there may be regulations that prescribe under which circumstances buyers can return goods to the sellers and get their money back. Also, punitive measures against fraudulent or negligent sellers are considered to be part of ex-post consumer protection. Such measures are particularly harsh in the USA. When in 1992 Stella Liebeck bought a cup of coffee for 49 cents in a Mcdonald's restaurant, the luckiest thing that happened to her was that she poured the coffee over her lap. This led to compensation payments (mainly “punitive damages”) of 2.86 million dollars to be paid by McDonald's to Ms. Liebeck (the case was later settled with a payment of several hundreds of thousands of dollars).

WHY CONSUMER PROTECTION?

In 2008, Chinese producers of baby milk wanted to pretend a high protein content of their product. To this end, the unscrupulous producers made use of the fact that the standard tests for protein content cannot distinguish between genuine protein and melamine, a chemical substance used as a fire retardant. So, they added melamine to the milk powder. This caused six babies to die, 54,000 babies had to be hospitalized, and 300,000 babies suffered from health problems. Some years before, watered-down baby milk led to the death of 13 babies due to malnutrition. The consequences were not only terrible for the affected babies and families, but they also damaged the reputation of Chinese food products.

Consumers often do not have the time and the expertise to make sure that they do not fall for a fraudulent seller. When entering an airplane, one just has to trust that the airline maintains the airplane in good shape and that the pilots are well-trained. It is a great service for passengers that government authorities shut down airlines that do not live up to high safety standards.

On the other hand, consumer protection laws can also be problematic if they are pushed by existing producers as a means to prevent imports (so-called “technical trade barriers”) or domestic competition. Moreover, they may impede innovation and they may be paternalistic for consumers.

THE NEW LAW IN GEORGIA

Currently, consumer protection can only be found in the “Code of Product Safety and Free Turnover” that was adopted in 2012, when the 1996 law on consumer protection was abolished. A new draft law that entails more comprehensive consumer protection is circulating in the ministries before it will be presented to the parliament. Let us look at some paragraphs of this draft law.

According to Article 6 of the copy of the draft law available to me, producers are required to provide information on how they calculated the price of the product. It says that the producer must provide “information on the total price of the product (including transportation, shipment, installation, etc.) or, where such price cannot be calculated in advance, on the components of the price and the methods of their calculation.”

From an economic point of view, forcing sellers to disclose their pricing is highly problematic. Pricing is one of the most closely guarded trade secrets, and this is fully legitimate. If a producer manages to utilize on a cost advantage, for example through a particular innovative production method or because of a cheap source of preliminary products, it would be a huge advantage for the competitors if this information would be revealed to them. As a consequence, incentives to improve the cost structure in innovative ways would largely disappear, as it would be much easier for competitors to copy those innovations if they know the cost structure of the innovator.

Even if domestic producers would abide by this regulation, it is not to be expected that foreign producers would disclose their cost structures because of Georgian law. The Georgian market has the volume of a medium-sized city in Europe or the USA, and companies will rather lose this market than disclose their pricing. While one may welcome some technical trade barriers in order to protect the Georgian industry, impediments of imports of goods that are not produced in Georgia (like most high-tech stuff) can cause serious strain for the Georgian economy.

Article 6 also requires that general information about the product and the producer must be in the Georgian language. While this is indeed an advantage for those Georgian consumers who do not speak Russian or English, it increases the costs of imports. One should also consider that if buyers of, say, computers would have a tangible desire for translated user manuals, sellers would have an incentive to do so without being forced by law. They could then charge higher prices for products with Georgian manuals.

Article 8 states: “The consumer shall have the right, except for special cases, to withdraw from the contract without giving reasons within 14 days after receiving the product”. This rule is clearly advantageous for consumers, but it will also increase prices. Sellers will anticipate that with some likelihood the product will come back within 14 days. If that happens, it may not always be possible to directly sell it again. Repackaging and testing of its functionality may be required. For sophisticated imported products that may be quite costly, as usually, the product has to be sent back to the manufacturer for restoring its salability.

On the other hand, if one wants to have a “right of return” at all (which most countries have and which is arguably necessary to prevent customers from being cheated), then Article 8 is nice and parsimonious. In other countries, customers are incentivized to intentionally damage the product they want to return because only then the law requires the seller to take it back. By not demanding the customer to give any reasons, there are no such futile incentives.

The views and analysis in this article belong solely to the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the international School of Economics at TSU (ISET) or ISET Policty Institute.
Subscribe